Monday, January 28, 2008

Social security for the unorganised sector Workers ?

A bill to provide social security to the unorganised sector workers is pending in the Parliament. A standing committee had scrutinised it and submitted their recommendations. The Left has rejected the Bill in its present form and wants the government to change the proposed legislation, which aims to cover 309 million workers.
because it does not incorporate committee's suggestions.

The Parliament Standing Committee on Labour invited suggestions, views, comments from individuals, institutions and organisations on the Unorganised Sector Workers' Social Security Bill, 2007. The Bill, introduced in Rajya Sabha on September 10, 2007, was referred to the Standing Committee on Labour under the Chairmanship of Lok Sabha MP, Suravaram Sudhakar Reddy for examination.

The Unorganized Sector Workers' Social Security Bill, 2007 talks about the social security and welfare of unorganized sector workers.

The bill provides for setting up of a National Social Security Advisory Board by the Central Government and the State Social Security Advisory Board by the State Governments respectively, for recommending suitable welfare schemes for different sections of unorganized sector workers.

A health insurance for workers of unorganised sector would be implemented from April 1. It provided a Rs 30,000 free health insurance cover to a five-member-family belonging to BPL category.


The labour ministry is reluctant to incorporate any major change suggested by the parliamentary standing committee.

The labour ministry doesn't see merit in the two main suggestions of the standing committee the creation of a dedicated fund for schemes for the sector and an administrative authority to implement these schemes.

Whether there is a dedicated fund or not is immaterial. Our only concern is availability of money. The government is already providing funds for the BPL (below poverty line) families. There is no shortage of funds,� said a top official in the labour ministry.

Ministry sources cite the example of the dedicated fund for north- eastern states. The huge amounts these funds are supposed to have are absent. Ministry officials say the welfare of unorganised labourers boils down to providing pension and life insurance. Since most of the schemes will be implemented by insurance companies and government agencies, there is no need to create another administrative body, they say.

The labour ministry says it has already extended old-age pension to all BPL families which is expected to cover a large section of unorganised workers. Then there is the Rashtriya Swasthya Bima Yojana for BPL families which will be functional from April 2008. After these schemes, where money for the beneficiaries� health needs is paid for, the government is framing schemes for other unorganised labourers.

We will soon moot schemes for autorickshaw drivers, domestic helps, fishermen, tailors, taxi-drivers and other unorganised sector workers. However, these schemes will be participatory,� said Union Labour Minister Oscar Fernandes.

Another important demand of the Left and the standing committee's separate arrangements for the agricultural workers is not a priority for the ministry. Most farmers or agricultural workers shift to other manual jobs in off-season, so it�s difficult to assess them as a different category, officials say.

A final decision on the recommendations of the standing committee will be taken by the Cabinet. We will try to pass the Bill in the coming session of Parliament, said Fernandes.

It is to be seen how much pressure the Left can exert on the government when the ministry is not ready to accept its major demands. A stubborn approach of the Left might stall the passage of the Bill and the Congress would have a political opportunity to campaign that the Left was obstructing the welfare of unorganised workers.

Business Standard reported on January 18, 2008 that “Pension scheme for mine workers” by April, 2008 is on the cards.

Impatient with parliamentary delay in passing the omnibus legislation for the unorganised labour, the labour ministry has decided to strike out on its own.

The ministry plans to launch a provident fund/pension scheme for mine and cine workers with contributions from both the worker and the government from April.

The scheme, under the rubric of the Unorganised Sector Workers’ Social Security Bill, comes amid the expectation that the enabling Bill will be passed during the Budget session of Parliament.

As labour is on the concurrent list, both the Centre and state governments can legislate on it. But the complaint has always been that state governments have been unable to sustain them because of a resource crunch. By claiming ownership of a scheme wholly funded by it, the Centre hopes to avoid that situation in the case of this scheme.

Initially, the scheme will cover around 500,000 mine and cine workers registered with the Labour Welfare Organisation. Later, all workers in the unorganised sector which constitutes 94 per cent of the country’s workforce will be brought under the scheme.

This is the first-of-its-kind scheme for the unorganised sector where the workers will also contribute a share. The ministry expects to bring a vast mass of the working population that has stayed outside the pale of the formal economy so far, under this scheme.

The scheme will be run by the labour ministry. Of the Rs 100 subscription per month, Rs 75 would be paid by the worker, while Rs 25 would be contributed through Labour Welfare Funds.

The government’s contribution for the pilot scheme covering two sectors is likely to cost around Rs 810 lakh annually. The funds will come from the labour ministry’s internal resources.

Workers of limestone, dolomite, iron/manganese/ chrome ore mines along with cine workers in the age group of 18 to 52 years, who are not already covered under a provident fund scheme of the government, are eligible under the scheme. Subscribers will be eligible for provident fund/pension at the age of 58.

�Workers will deposit the monthly premium in a designated post office/bank or with the Labour Welfare Organisation�s dispensaries. The money would be transferred to UTI which would act as the fund manager of the corpus created from the contribution from workers and government,� a labour department official said.

UTI will provide the members’ list to the Welfare Commissioners who will deposit the central government’s share, as a subsidy, with UTI periodically.

The worker would be eligible for a lump sum amount at the time of maturity, equivalent to the value of the units issued to him by UTI from time to time. An option for a pension scheme in lieu of the lump sum amount will also be provided to the worker.

The only other pension scheme for unorganised labour is the government’s proposal to pay Rs 200 per month to all below the poverty line (BPL) persons above 65 under the National Old Age Pension Scheme.

There is no structured contributory pension/provident fund schemes for workers in unorganised sector. So, the ministry is working on a scheme to provide old age security to this segment of unorganised workers.

As the scheme is contributory, a worker is free to join any other scheme as well. In case of default, the deposited money will not be confiscated and the member can rejoin the scheme later.

A member is eligible for pension only after attaining 58 years of age which will be paid through a bank or post office. If a worker wants to withdraw his money, he is free to do so but in such cases he will not get the pension and is only eligible to get his deposits and growth amount subject to deduction of 1 per cent exit load.


Background to Omnibus legislation for the unorganised labour based on a PIB Release

A survey conducted by the National Sample Survey Organization (NSSO), shows that the total employment in both the organized and the unorganised sectors in the country is 39.7 crore, of which 2.8 crore are in the organized sector and 36.9 crore (about 93%) are in the unorganised sector. Of this, 23.7 crore workers are in the agricultural sector and 1.7 crore are engaged in construction sector. Remaining workers are engaged in mining, manufacturing and services sector. On account of their unorganised nature, these workers do not get adequate social security and welfare.

Some welfare schemes are being implemented by the Central Government for specific occupational groups of unorganised sector workers such as beedi workers, non-coal mine workers, cine workers, handloom weavers, fishermen, etc. These are apart from the National old Age Pension Scheme and National Rural Health Mission. Some of the State Governments have also been implementing welfare programmes for certain categories of the unorganised sector workers. Some NGOs are also providing social security to certain categories of workers. Despite all these efforts, there is a deficit in the coverage of the unorganised sector workers in the matter of labour protection and social security measures.

THE MANDATE OF NCMP

In line with the commitment made by the United Progressive Alliance (UPA) Government in the National Common Minimum Programme (NCMP), the National Commission for Enterprises in the Unorganised Sector (NCEUS) was set up in September 2004 under the chairmanship of Dr. Arjun Sengupta as an advisory body and as a watchdog for the unorganized sector. The Commission has the mandate to examine the problems of the unorganized sector (also referred to as informal sector) and suggest measures to overcome them. The term of the Commission, which was initially fixed at one year, was extended to three years. The Commission has been assigned wide-ranging terms of reference. Being an advisory body, the Commission is supposed to submit its recommendations to the Government of India. An Advisory Board has also been constituted to enable the Commission to have the benefit of the advice of experienced persons in the relevant areas.

The Commission has been focusing on a few significant programmatic interventions, which could be adopted in the immediate term. These interventions are aimed at bringing about improvement in the productivity of enterprises in the unorganized/Informal Sector, generation of large-scale employment opportunities on a sustainable basis and enhancing the welfare of the workers in the unorganized sector.

COMMISSION’S FINDINGS

The Commission’s findings show that forty per cent of the workers in the unorganised agricultural and non-agricultural sector are wage workers and sixty per cent are self-employed. Among the self-employed, the overwhelming majorities are own account or assisting family workers and only 1.15 % (among non-agricultural workers) are employers.

The vast majority of the self-employed in the unorganised sector themselves work under poor conditions and the productivity of their enterprises is very low. Measures to protect the livelihood of the self-employed workers and to promote the productivity of the unorganised enterprises, will not only have an impact on the condition of the self-employed, but also on the condition of the unorganised wage workers who work in the unorganised enterprises. Thus, regulation of the condition of work of wage workers needs to go hand in hand with the protection and promotion of livelihood of the self-employed workers and enhancing the growth and productivity of the unorganised sector enterprises.

PROPOSED BILLS

The Commission had initially proposed a draft Bill “Unorganised Sector Workers (Conditions of Work & Livelihood Promotion) Bill, 2005” for comments and feedback. Based on the comments received from states, trade unions and other stake holders, the Commission revised the earlier proposal and has now proposed two Bills “Unorganised Non-agricultural Sector Workers (Conditions of Work and Livelihood Promotion) Bill, 2007” and the “Unorganised Agricultural Sector Workers (Conditions of Work and Livelihood Promotion) Bill, 2007” to cover unorganised agricultural workers and non-agricultural workers respectively. Part 1 of each of the Bills contains provisions relating to the regulation of conditions of work of wage workers. Part 2 of the Bill relates to the protection and promotion of livelihoods of the unorganised workers.

The Draft Bills provide for basic and minimum conditions of work for all unorganised wage workers and home workers. Instead of relying on bureaucratic implementation and costly and time consuming legal redressal procedures, the Commission has accorded priority to conciliation and has proposed the participation of workers’ representatives and elected representatives of the local bodies in the conciliation and dispute resolution committees.

The proposed Bills also mandate that the appropriate governments take the necessary steps to protect and promote these livelihoods through appropriate policies and programmes, and have provided for an institutional machinery to take a holistic view of the sector and to mobilise the necessary resources to help the sector overcome such constraints and facilitate its growth.

NATIONAL FUND

The NCEUS has proposed the formation of a National Fund designed to meet the multi purpose needs of both enterprises and workers in the unorganized sector. The tasks proposed to be handled by the Fund are extensive as the sector needs a holistic approach for its development taking into account all essential needs covering finance, technology, raw material, marketing, infrastructure, skill and entrepreneurship and would cover both farm and non-farm sectors and also rural and urban areas.

CABINET NOD FOR SOCIAL SECURITY

In a significant move the Union Cabinet on 24th May, 2007 gave its approval for social security for the unorganised sector workers. It said that the welfare schemes for workers in the unorganized sector would be introduced in a phased manner to fulfil the commitment made in the National Common Minimum Programme. Besides, the Government would constitute a National Advisory Board to design, from time to time, suitable welfare schemes for different sections of unorganized workers and recommend the same to the Government. On the recommendations of the National Advisory Board, the Central Government will, from time to time, notify scheme or schemes for one or more sections of unorganized workers.

Apart from designing model schemes for workers in unorganized sector, the National Advisory Board shall monitor the implementation of all notified welfare schemes; ensure that every eligible worker in the unorganized sector is registered and receives an identity card; oversee the record keeping functions performed at the district level and the State level.

The Cabinet also paved the way for a Bill to be introduced in Parliament as early as possible for this purpose. The Bill would provide for setting up a National Advisory Board and enable the Central Government to notify welfare schemes from time to time.

The Bill will also provide for constitution of a State Level Advisory Board by the State Government concerned.

The schemes notified by the Central Government will contain provisions for: (a) life and disability cover; (b) health benefits; (c) old age protection; or (d) any other benefit as decided by the Central Govt.

The procedure for registering the workers in the unorganized sector will be prescribed and implemented. Every worker in the unorganized sector shall be eligible for registration subject to the following conditions: (a) he/she should have completed 18 years of age; (b) he/she should make a self-declaration affirming that he/she is a worker in the unorganized sector.

Every registered worker in the unorganized sector shall be issued an identity card, which shall be a smart card. It shall carry a unique identification number and shall be portable.

The record-keeping agency for this purpose shall be the district administration and the record keeping function shall be performed by the District Panchayat in rural areas, and Urban Local Bodies in urban areas. This will be directed by the concerned State Governments.

These schemes and proposed Bill/Bills, if introduced, will go a long way to mitigate the plight of the unorganized workers in the country.

Friday, January 18, 2008

Public health in private hands? A note on the Public Health Foundation of India

Speaking for Ourselves 221

MOHAN RAO, K. R. NAYAR

We live in a world of profound, and growing, inequalities. Changes in the global economy over the past three decades have been accompanied by dramatic reversals of health gains made in the post-Second World War period. While some countries have witnessed stagnation in health indices, others have seen dramatic declines. At the same time, what is termed the health divide—between rich nations and poor nations, and between the rich and poor within countries—is increasing remarkably. Thus, for example, the gap in the under-5 death rate, considered a sensitive indicator of social and economic development, has widened between the rich countries and the poor. The under-5 death rate gap increased from a ratio of 7.8 in 1978 to 12.5 in 1998. Similarly, the death rate ratio in the age group 5–14 years also increased from 3.8 in 1950 to 7 in 1990.

It is widely accepted that these widening health inequalities are the consequence of the imposition of the World Bank and International Monetary Fund (IMF)-led policies of structural adjustment and the accompanying health sector reforms around the globe. Over the same period, the role of the WHO has shrunk, with the World Bank increasingly setting the agenda for health. World Bank loans for one disease alone, malaria, exceed the entire budget of the WHO.

In addition to reducing state commitment to health, typically, these health prescriptions of the World Bank are committed to methodological individualism and to behaviourism; they do not recognize the structural factors that govern and contour the health or ecology of disease. As a result, interventions tend to be disjointed (oral rehydration solution [ORS] for diarrhoea rather than emphasizing on water supply and sanitation; focusing on anaemia in pregnancy, but not anaemia in the general population), and of a technical nature—what is referred to as the biomedical approach in public health. This has led to the growth of disease-centric vertical programmes. Globally—and reflected even in India’s National Health Policy 2002—it is recognized that one of the failures of health sector development in the past has been due to such vertical programme approaches. Assuming there is a grave fiscal crisis—which still seems to allow for subsidies to be given to the rich in a variety of areas—these prescriptions typically include fee for services. Again, the global experience has been that this excludes the poor from access to health services. Indeed, it is this explicit recognition that has led countries such as Zambia to do away with this policy prescription. What the package of prescriptions tends to do is to wrench apart comprehensive public healthcare, entrust profitable sectors of it to the private sector and enjoin the state to subsidize a minimum clinical package, which typically involves family planning.

The global experience with this approach to health sector development has been dismal, and not just in poor countries. In Russia, following the neo-liberal changes in the economy and the accompanying health sector reforms, between 1991 and 1994, life expectancy among men decreased by close to 7 years, from 63.6 to 57.5 years; among women the decline was close to 3 years, from 74.4 to 71.1 years. Such a decline in life expectations in populations not at war or suffering the onslaught of that other horse of the apocalypse, famine, is historically unprecedented. Accompanying the collapse of under-funded systems of healthcare, a booming private health system has emerged, along with a resurgence of old communicable diseases and hunger. Indeed, even in the USA, data on life expectancy by race, a crude indicator of inequality, shows increasing divergence between whites and blacks beginning in the Reagan years. The most telling data are from the UK that reveal increasing mortality differentials by class. The Black Report showed a substantial increase in mortality differentials by social class; the mortality rates among unskilled working-class men in 1981 were higher than they had ever been in the twentieth century, deteriorating after 1971.

This is despite the fact that developed countries spend much more on health than India does, not only in absolute per capita terms but also as shares of national income or public budgets. The UK spends 6% of its budget on health, India now less than 1%. In contrast, the USA spends 12% of its budget on health. The UK relies on universal coverage and a state-supported and -led National Health Service. It has better health indices than the USA despite spending less on health. In the USA, for instance, about 40 million people obtain no health coverage. Infant mortality rates (IMRs) and under-5 mortality rates (U5MR) are significantly higher than in the UK. This calls for re-thinking of some neo-liberal shibboleths such as the supposed inefficiency of the public sector and the greater efficiency of market-driven private behaviour. Sri Lanka offers an excellent example of state-led quality healthcare provision. In Sri Lanka, about 97% of inpatient care and 83% of outpatient care is in the public sector, where they have also integrated the so-called indigenous systems of medicine.

India is yet to achieve the National Health Policy 1983 target of reducing the IMR to less than 60 per 1000 live births. More serious is the fact that the rate of decline in the IMR, which was significant in the 1970s and 1980s, has markedly decelerated in the 1990s. The percentage decline in IMR between 1971 and 1981 was 14.7; between 1981 and 1991 it was even greater at 27.3. However, in the period 1991–99, there has been a stagnation, with the rate of decline in the IMR at 10%. Similarly, while there has been a decline in the U5MR, the pace of decline has come down and the U5MR is currently hovering around 95. During 1971–81, the percentage decline was 20.6. The decline was much sharper during the 1980s, with a percentage decline of 35.7. However, during the 1990s, with the onset of policies of liberalization, the rate of decline fell to 15.1.1

Other changes have been equally important. Interregional, rural–urban, gender and economic class differentials in access to healthcare in India are well documented. But since the onset of liberalization policies, these have widened considerably. The decline in public investments was matched by growing subsidies to the private sector in healthcare in a variety of ways.2 State support for private healthcare grew with the initiation of private–public partnerships that took a variety of forms. At the same time, there were far-reaching changes in drug policies. Thus India—earlier characterized by relatively low costs of drugs and pharmaceuticals, along with major indigenous production of drugs—has witnessed a greater concentration of drug production, a larger role for multinationals, a higher proportion of imported drugs and unbelievably steep rises in the costs of drugs.3 Concurrently, marked shifts have occurred in healthcare utilization. Among people who sought outpatient services in 1995–96, more than 80% did so in the private sector, a sharp increase in even the poorer states of the country.4 In 1995–96, 55% and 57% of people in rural and urban areas, respectively, were hospitalized in the private sector compared to 40% in 1986–87. The National Sample Survey (NSS) data indicate greater inequality in the use of health facilities by economic class gradients. In rural areas the class gradient in inpatient use of public hospitals—which was insignificant in the mid-1980s—turned statistically significant in the mid-1990s. In urban areas, inequality in the use of public facilities did not worsen significantly, but inequality in the use of private facilities did. The steep fall in rural hospitalization rates, along with increasing use by the better-off indicates that the poor are being squeezed out. Fee-for-services is undoubtedly one important mechanism that has succeeded in doing this. In other words, World Bank policies on health, contained in the influential World development report 1993 succeeded in doing exactly the opposite of what was ostensibly its raison d’ĂȘtre: reduce the utilization of public services by the better-off to increase access
to the poor.

Costs of both outpatient and inpatient care have increased sharply in both rural and urban areas, compared to the mid-1980s. Private outpatient costs increased by 142% as against 77% in the public sector in rural areas. In urban areas, private outpatient costs increased by 150% compared to 124% in the public sector. The increase in costs in inpatient care is even more striking: average costs rose by 436% in rural and 320% in urban areas.4 Thus, it is not surprising that, as the National Health Policy 2002 notes, medical expenditure has emerged as one of the leading causes of indebtedness.5 At the same time, the proportion of people not availing any type of medical care due to financial reasons between 1986–87 and 1995–96 increased from 10% to 21% in urban areas, and from 15% to 24% in rural areas.6

What we need is state-led support to primary healthcare in all its dimensions. Efforts to do so through the National Rural Health Mission appear diminished in vision, and totally lack a systemic perspective. It is also seriously underfunded. Thus, the need is to concentrate on strengthening the entire primary healthcare (PHC) system—which includes efficient referral systems to secondary and tertiary levels of care. State governments are facing huge financial problems in doing so. There are massive shortages of human resources such as public health nurses, auxiliary nurse–midwives, male multipurpose workers, etc. not to mention specialists. This is especially the case in states with poor health indices. Given the low financial outlays, a large part of the health budget goes towards salaries. Without resources, time, support staff and drugs to provide effective public healthcare, doctors lose motivation and seek alternative work. In this situation the PHC system offers little other than family planning and oral polio vaccination, driving people, the poor included, into the private sector. In this situation of state-led collapse of the public health structure, community initiatives are both inadequate and regressive. Accredited social health activists (ASHAs) cannot function in a dysfunctional healthcare system. A further drain on public resources is through knee-jerk initiatives such as increasing public–private partnerships (PPP) or ‘NGOization’.

It is against this backdrop that the effort to create a Public Health Foundation of India (PHFI) needs to be critically examined. This is apparently an autonomous institution with 15% of funds from the government and the rest from other sources. State governments are expected to provide land and other infrastructure facilities. The PHFI will create 5 new institutions for training in public health, commencing initially with 2 schools. We understand that recruitment of faculty has already commenced in schools of public health in the USA (the last date for applications was 9 March 2006, as per a circular to Deans and Assistant Deans of schools of public health in the USA; the PHFI was inaugurated on 28 March 2006).

There are a number of issues with regard to the new-found love for world-class ‘India-centric, India-relevant and tailored to India’ public health. It is apparent that dual systems of healthcare will now extend to dual systems of training in public health. This includes possibly dual salary structures, leading to internal brain drain.
The question that needs to be seriously considered is the system of public health that is now being considered worthy of emulation. As we noted earlier, one model of healthcare that should not to be emulated is the American model. It is not only much more expensive, but also leaves out substantial sections of the population. Indeed, it would not be an exaggeration to state that the aim of the American system of public health is the creation of markets in healthcare. Under the influence of such a system, the global industry in health has increased from US$ 396 billion in 1976 to US$ 786 billion in 1990.

It is in this context that one should examine the role of the Harvard School of Public Health, indeed, the American system of public health schools, in shaping public health education and research in India and in many other developing countries, including China. Scholars such as Hugh Leavell, Benjamin Paul, John Gordon, Carl Taylor, Theodore Ingalls, James Simmons and John Wyon, collectively known as the ‘Harvard group’, were instrumental in shaping the population control agenda with a neo-Malthusian bias in the early 1960s. The damage this has caused to health sector development in India is well known. Their enthnocentrism was evident when one of their influential studies concluded: ‘Westerners have strong feelings about the value of children not shared by Punjabi villagers.’7

However, perhaps more important is the shaping of the curriculum of Preventive and Social Medicine by scholars such as Carl Taylor who chaired the Department of Preventive and Social Medicine (PSM) of the Christian Medical College in Ludhiana. No doubt, at that time as well, the curriculum was India-relevant as it was based on the well-known ‘internship studies’ undertaken by the Harvard group. The approach was strikingly similar to colonial anthropology, that of studying the ‘natives’.8 A survey undertaken in 1959 of the teaching of PSM revealed that rural internship programmes were in serious trouble. It was found that rural health centres for training interns had evolved without proper planning. The major problems were inadequate staffing, equipment and accommodation. There was widespread apathy among the interns regarding the purpose of the programme. Following this, a project on rural orientation of physicians was undertaken on a request from the Minister of Health, Government of India by the PSM Department of the Ludhiana Medical College under the leadership of Carl Taylor. The project was funded through a PL-480 grant from the Bureau of Educational and Cultural Affairs of the United States Department of State. The study reinforced the internship approach by expanding the practical training over 4 levels of facilities: teaching hospitals, average district hospitals, teaching health centres and average health centres, and suggested the philosophy of ‘medical colleges without walls’. Despite such heavy foreign funding and American ‘wheat’ funding, the quality of public health teaching could not be salvaged.

The intervention of the Medical Council of India (MCI) and recommendations of the Srivastava Committee led to further shifts in the teaching of public health in medical colleges. The important shift was the introduction of the Reorientation of Medical Education (ROME) scheme in 1977. The objectives of the ROME scheme were to involve medical colleges in direct delivery of health services to the rural population as well as expose students to the rural environment. Some foreign governments even donated huge mobile clinics for rural areas under the programme, which of course did not serve the purpose since these large vans could not traverse narrow, unpaved rural roads. The ROME scheme was implemented initially in 25 medical colleges and was extended to all the medical colleges recognized by the MCI. It can now be safely asserted that the present poor state of PSM education in medical colleges in India and the failure to produce a ‘managerial physician’ could be attributed to the original sin committed in the 1950s. Further cosmetic changes did not succeed due to the poorly envisioned curriculum that continued to remain unattractive.

It is evident that without strengthening the existing public health teaching in medical colleges—there are 120 of them throughout the country at present—it will be impossible to create a ‘managerial physician’ who needs to provide effective leadership in the health services system. An elite-oriented public health education on such a large scale and in a vertical fashion may not achieve such an objective.

It appears that planners in India seek to bring back this variety of American-exported public health. Once famously described as a-theoretical, a-political and a-historical, this is now touted as a model for ‘high impact public health research’. It is also not accidental that many American and European schools of public
(one can see the table published in the original article at www.nmji.in/archives/volume_19_4_Jul_Aug_2006/speaking_for_myself/Public%20health.pdf)
health (based on the so-called ‘hygiene’ and ‘tropical’ medicine models) that have been cornering international research funds for ‘sanitizing’ and intellectually ‘colonizing’ many African countries are looking for new markets for their knowledge.

The PHFI initiative also aims to create a capacity to train 10 000 people per year in public health by offering long and short term programmes with multiple degrees such as certificates, diplomas, masters, doctorates, etc. Is this what India actually needs? If we look at the manpower requirement in rural primary healthcare, it becomes evident that most shortages are those of ‘low-level’ primary care staff such as nurses and male health workers (Table I). Can such high-profile institutes provide the personnel needed to manage primary healthcare services? There is no doubt that the duality in public health education will breed elitism and produce an unfit and unwanted class of professionals. What it will also do is produce public health staff for the First World, at a cheaper price. Currently 4000–5000 doctors trained at public expense emigrate every year, at an estimated cost of US$ 160 million to the Indian exchequer.9

It is also necessary to mention the role of private foundation funding in this whole process. For instance, the Bill and Melinda Gates Foundation is a major partner in PHFI. The ‘grand challenges’ proposed by the Gates Foundation have turned critical challenges in public health into a narrowly conceived understanding of health as the product of technical interventions divorced from the economic, social and epidemiological contexts.10 Six of the 14 grand challenges in public health relate to vaccine development. It is possible that such a narrow technology-driven vision of public health will be the paradigmatic basis of the grand new public health in future. Should such a public health orientation set standards and determine the accreditation of public health education in India as has been proposed through the PHFI? When the market starts dominating the discourse of public health, it will only undermine academic autonomy as is already the case in management education.11 Indeed, it will create a discipline based on the rules and games of the market including profits and student-customers who can buy such an education.

A further substantial part of the PHFI’s budget is to come from unspecified private sector contributions. This is even more undesirable as it will distort public health priorities even further towards profitable interventions alone. Examples are legion of private sector funding skewing research agendas and findings. Thus, for instance, the ban on routine inclusion of antibiotics in animal feed in order to reduce antibiotic resistance in the general human population, effected in England after the outbreak of bovine spongiform encephalitis (mad cow disease), has been bitterly contested by public health scientists in the USA on the basis of research funded by the animal foods industry.12

It is not our argument that public health training does not need strengthening or that institutionalized education in this matter is not necessary. Both are very important. However, before we set up new institutions at great cost—whatever the source of funds—we must examine what ails the existing system. India already has institutions such as the National Institute of Health and Family Welfare, the National Tuberculosis Institute, the All India Institute of Hygiene and Public Health and so forth—some of which did remarkable public health work in the past. There are, however, problems with many of these institutions, such as lack of funds, lack of autonomy and so on, which need to be dealt with. Without doing so, to start new institutions is not only undesirable, but in a situation of fund constraint, also hugely wasteful economically.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
Our grateful thanks to Jayati Ghosh for her comments. She is, however, not to be besmirched by the weaknesses of our arguments—or infelicities in them.

REFERENCES

1. Misra R, Chatterjee R, Rao S. India health report. New Delhi:Oxford University Press; 2003.
2. Baru R. Private health in India: Social characteristics and trends. New Delhi:Sage; 1998.
3. Sengupta A. Economic reforms, health and pharmaceuticals. Economic Political Weekly 1996;31:3155–9.
4. Sen G, Iyer A, George A. Class, gender and health equity: Lessons from liberalising India. In: Sen G, George A, Ostlin P (eds). Engendering international health. Massachusetts:MIT Press; 2002:281–312.
5. Government of India, Ministry of Health and Family Welfare. National health policy. New Delhi:Ministry of Health and Family Welfare; 2002.
6. Government of India, Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation. Note on morbidity and treatment of ailments: NSS 52nd round (July 1995–June 1996). Sarvekshana 2000;XXIII:59–67.
7. Wyon JB, Gordan JE. The Khanna study: Population problems in rural Punjab. Cambridge, Massachusetts:Harvard University Press; 1971.
8. Qadeer I, Nayar KR. Politics of pedagogy in public health. Social Scientist 2005:33:47–75.
9. Voluntary Health Association of India. Report of the Independent Commission on Health in India. New Delhi:Voluntary Health Association of India; 1997.
10. Birn A-E. Gates’s grandest challenge: Transcending technology as public health ideology. Lancet 2005;366:514–19.
11. Editorial. Higher education: From politics to market. Economic Political Weekly 2006;XLI:669.
12. Walters MJ. Six modern plagues: And how we are causing them. Washington:
Island Press; 2004.

Centre of Social Medicine and Community Health, School of Social Sciences, Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi 110067, India. mohanrao@mail.jnu.ac.in

Published in VOLUME 19, NUMBER 4 JULY/AUGUST2006, The National Medical Journal of India


Public health needs a boost, not bickering

Speaking for Ourselves 224
K. SRINATH REDDY

Because things are the way they are,
things will not stay the way they are.
— Bertolt Brecht

It is difficult to disagree with passionate champions of public health such as Mohan Rao and Nayar. There is also no cause to disagree when they argue, in the initial part of their viewpoint exposition, that the social determinants of health and disease need to be identified and addressed through fundamental social changes that promote equity, access and affordability as essential characteristics of the health system. There is no dispute also when they argue for the strengthening of primary healthcare and affirm that it is governments that bear the major responsibility for ensuring the availability of healthcare to all sections of the people, through appropriately structured and adequately financed public health services.

There could be some minor differences, however, when they posit oral rehydration solution (ORS) and provision of safe water and sanitation as mutually exclusive public health programmes. While it is undoubtedly important to advocate, aim for and accomplish sustainable social promoters of health such as universal supply of safe drinking water, interventions such as ORS could still save thousands of young children who may fall victim to diarrhoea, till that salutary social objective is achieved. Obsession with technology should never drive public health polices or programmes, which need to address the determinants of health rather than merely attempt quick-fix solutions for disease. At the same time, public health should never shun appropriate use of suitable technologies to advance towards its goals.

Similarly, prevention and amelioration of anaemia in the general population, through policies for improvement of mass nutrition and creation of hygienic conditions where parasitic diseases are avoided, is a laudable and necessary objective. Till that goal is achieved, would not special attention to the detection and correction of anaemia in an especially vulnerable group of pregnant women, who run a high risk of pregnancy-related complications and death, serve a useful public health purpose? Public health needs a broad array of interventions which can make complementary contributions to create a comprehensive response to complex health challenges. An ‘either–or’ approachcan be self-defeating and may freeze the status quo till major social changes can successfully influence all of the social determinants.

However, my major area of discord with Mohan Rao and Nayar’s writing arises only when it strays from being a sound social critique, which it is in the initial section, to become a string of speculative comments on the role of the Public Health Foundation of India (PHFI) in the latter part of the article. The criticism of PHFI is based on assumptions that the PHFI Institutes would (i) follow an American model of education, (ii) produce public health professionals for an export market, (iii) create a cadre of elitist ‘managerial physicians’ distanced from primary healthcare, (iv) promote a technology-driven biomedical model of public health, and (v) result in neglect of existing public health training institutions.

None of the above assumptions are valid. The PHFI will mainly draw upon Indian experience and Indian expertise, while drawing up its curriculum and developing its learning resources. Future faculty would be drawn from available expertise in India and others trained abroad, in multiple reputed centres across the world. PHFI would establish academic partnerships with public health institutions from all regions of the world and access global learnings which are robust in academic content as well as relevant to the Indian context. Connectivity with public health institutions in other developing countries would be accorded a high priority. No exclusive relationship has been established with any American school of public health and each PHFI Institute will connect with a number of Indian and international partners. In the overall context of public health education, it is useful to draw upon the strengths of international partners, including American schools where appropriate, in core disciplines such as epidemiology, health economics, biostatistics and behavioural sciences. We should remember that American universities are also home to persons such as Amartya Sen, Noam Chomsky and Joseph Stiglitz, who are respected for their independent thinking and contributions to public discourse. Similarly, American universities also house many public health teachers and researchers who are not inimical to the interests of developing countries such as India. It is for us to evolve the models of education most relevant to us and engage with those who can help us in the areas of our identified needs. Countries such as Thailand, Iran and Bangladesh have much to teach us and we will learn from them, as we will also learn from institutions in Europe, North America and Australia.

Initially, the majority of those trained in the PHFI Institutes would be persons already employed in the State health services or health NGOs. The aim would be to add value to their role as serving functionaries in the health system. Simultaneously, efforts would be made to persuade states to create definitive positions for persons with public health expertise, so that even fresh graduates can be absorbed. The creation of a public health cadre has been recommended by several expert committees (Bhore Committee, 1946; Mudaliar Committee 1961; the Expert Committee on Public Health System 1996, constituted by the Government of India). PHFI would advocate for the creation of such a cadre, even while training existing physician and non-physician public health functionaries who are presently positioned in the health system. There would also be efforts to increase the absorption of public health professionals into the voluntary and private sectors in India. The purpose is to invigorate all components of the Indian health system with infusion of public health expertise.

Far from creating ‘elitist physician managers’, PHFI aims to provide multidisciplinary education and training to a wide range of public health resource persons. In a situation where neither nurses nor nutritionists have a major programme for training in public health and where public health law and public health engineering are rudimentary disciplines, PHFI hopes to evolve innovative models of education. Health management too would be an important educational stream, but only as one among several that PHFI would nurture.

In the present scenario, where are the programmes that can inform and influence sectors such as agriculture and urban planning to address public health needs? How many health economists are available in India to conduct policy-relevant studies and document the effects of distorted development on the health of the people, leave aside teach courses in this much-needed but almost non-existent discipline? At the grassroots, how many trained personnel are available for nationwide disease surveillance? Why are cause-specific mortality data not available for many common diseases? Training programmes are obviously needed at many levels and PHFI would try to facilitate them, along with other institutions.

The fact that PHFI derives a part of its initial funding from the Gates Foundation cannot be construed as evidence that its public health education programmes would have a tubular technovision. The broad-based education that PHFI envisages will encompass a clear understanding of the multiple determinants of health and provide the skill sets for undertaking multisectoral actions to advance public health. The Gates grant is an unrestricted grant and does not bind PHFI to any particular pattern of education or research.

PHFI is also committed to assist the growth of existing and other emerging public health training institutions in India. It would help to create a network of such institutions which can strengthen each other through sharing of technical expertise and conduct conjoint programmes in teaching and research. It must be recognized that the existing institutional strength in public health education and training is highly inadequate for developing human resources on a scale needed to transform the health services. If the present institutions were fully capable of delivering all that is required, why would the prevailing scene be so dismal both in terms of the available public health workforce and public health advocacy? Whether for advocating policy change or for implementing programmes, many more public health professionals are needed to generate and apply knowledge as relevant to public health goals.

Finally, it is misleading to suggest that PHFI has been created to place public health in private hands. The primary objective of PHFI is to strengthen public health services. The partnership with the Central and State Governments and their participation in the governance of PHFI and its institutes will ensure that the activities of PHFI are closely aligned to the priorities identified by the government and will readily respond to the needs of public health services. A number of State Governments have already communicated their interest in establishing such a close partnership. The voice of civil society would also be heard and heeded when it provides its inputs through various advisory bodies which would soon be established. It is only when public health continues to be neglected that the health of the people will be mostly transferred to private hands, by default. The PHFI’s mandate is to protect public health, not to undermine it.

To let the ‘status quo’ continue, because of false insecurity about new institutions or misplaced fears about hidden agendas, would be a grave disservice to the Indian people. To deliver an advance verdict of ‘guilt by suspicion’ on PHFI, even before it has started functioning, reflects neither natural justice nor scientific objectivity.

A new initiative should be judged neither by the best hopes of its friends nor the worst fears of its critics but by the reality of its activities as they unfold. It would be better for skeptics to closely monitor the activities of the PHFI, which is just born, and reserve their judgement till it opens its first Institute in 2008. It would be best, of course, if all well-meaning advocates of public health join hands and promote a sound framework for addressing India’s many health challenges.

Public Health Foundation of India, New Delhi, India; ksreddy@ccdcindia.org

Published in VOLUME 19, NUMBER 4 JULY/AUGUST2006, The National Medical Journal of India